Friday 8 March 2013

Environmental economics


Economics is a body of knowledge (a science) that has certain theories, values, methods, and assumptions. One goal of economists is to understand how to produce goods for society in the most efficient manner.  This is achieved by having a better understanding of human activities in a market system.  

Environmental economics is the study of environmental uses and abuses as viewed through the lens of economics. Typical economic concerns, such as market failure, externality, or valuation, are applied to environmental topics. Topics studied include things like pollution, consumption and alternative forms of energy. One of the big concerns of today is that people are taking too much from the earth without giving enough back. The goal of environmental economics is to discover a balance between the least amount of usage and the greatest societal benefit.

Valuation in Environmental Economics

One of the big issues in environmental economics is determining the value of natural resources. Some things, such as oil, have an actual monetary value assigned to it, and many things have a value based on their use and indirect use. However, it can be nearly impossible to determine the value of having a green Earth for future generations. This is especially true since such a concept may have an infinite value to some, but be worthless to others. Other natural things, such as the value of an intact ozone layer or a lack of pollution, are intangible and therefore without a price tag.

Cost Benefit Analyses in Environmental Economics

The use of natural resources and the degradation of the environment is an expected part of life. Modern living relies heavily on energy and a variety of nonrenewable materials, and side effects such as pollution are inevitable. Though such expenditures are by no means good or healthy, they are a necessary part of life and needed for the advancement of society. Some people focus solely on reducing the carbon footprint, but environmental economists perform cost benefit analyses instead. At times, mild environmental ruin may be worth great economic benefit.

The Relevance of Externality to Environmental Economics

In economics, the concept of externality refers to a cost or benefit incurred by someone other than the buyer or seller. This effect is generally not accounted for in the price the buyer paid. A positive externality provides a benefit; a negative externality results in a cost to society. The famous story of Erin Brokovich’s case with the Hinkley groundwater contamination is a great example of a negative externality. A third party, the residents of Hinkley, suffered debilitating medical conditions from contaminated water, and this cost not included in the price the buyers paid.

Environmentalists work on reducing the overall carbon footprints without giving any thought as to how that reduction will affect society’s ability to produce and advance. Economists work to ensure the best financial situation for the maximum number of people. Environmental economists combine the two fields, encouraging economic and societal advancement without forgetting the effect they may be having on the environment.

Detailed Note

Environmental economics is a distinct branch of economics that acknowledges the value of both the environment and economic activity and makes choices based on those values.  The goal is to balance the economic activity and the environmental impacts by taking into account all the costs and benefits.  The theories are designed to take into account pollution and natural resource depletion, which the current model of market systems fails to do. This “failure” needs to be addressed by correcting prices so they take into account “external” costs.  External costs are uncompensated side effects of human actions.  For example, if a stream is polluted by runoff from agricultural land, the people downstream suffer a negative external cost or externality.
The assumption in environmental economics is that the environment provides resources (renewable and non-renewable), assimilates waste, and provides aesthetic pleasure to humans.  These are economic functions because they have positive economic value and could be bought and sold in the market place.  However, traditionally, their value was not recognized because there is no market for these services (to establish a price), which is why economists talk about “market failure”.   Market failure is defined as the inability of markets to reflect the full social costs or benefits of a good, service, or state of the world.  Therefore, when markets fail, the result will be inefficient or unfavorable allocation of resources.   Since economic theory wants to achieve efficiency, environmental economics is used as a tool to find a balance in the world’s system of resource use. 
Another basic term in environmental economics is the idea of “scarcity.”  Historically,  goods and services provided by the environment were seen to be limitless, having no cost, thus not considered scarce.  Scarcity is a misallocation of these services (which are not limitless) due to a pricing problem.  If resources were properly priced to include all costs, then the resource could not be over-exploited because the actual cost would be too high.  This is a powerful tool in environmental problems…proper pricing.  
Environmental economics is not the same as ecological economics.  Ecological economics is a new model with the basic premise being that market-based activities are not sustainable, so a “grand new theory” is needed to describe the world and determine how to conduct activities in a sustainable manner.  It uses an entirely different framework.  This paper will discuss only environmental economics.
The key to the environmental economics approach is that there is value from the environment and value from the economic activity…the goal is to balance the economic activity with environmental degradation by taking all costs and benefits into account.

What is environmental valuation?
In order to help correct economic decisions that often treat environmental functions as free, it is important to define and measure their value. Valuation measures human preferences for or against changes in the state of environments.  It does not value the environment on its own.   If there is no human attachment to it, then the service has no economic value.  Although other types of value are often important, economic values are useful to consider when making economic choices – choices that involve tradeoffs in allocating resources.  
“Measures of economic value are based on what people want – their preferences.  
Economists generally assume that individuals, not the government, are the best judges 
of what they want.  Thus, the theory of economic valuation is based on individual 
preferences and choices.  People express their preferences through the choices and 
tradeoffs that they make, given certain constraints, such as those on income or available 
time. In a market economy, dollars (or some other currency) are a universally accepted 
measure of economic value, because the number of dollars that a person is willing to pay 
for something tells how much of all other goods and services they are willing to give up to 
get that item. This is often referred to as ‘willingness to pay.’”   

Many economists have been criticized for putting a ‘price tag’ on nature.  However, decisions are being made every minute regarding resource allocation.  These decisions are economic decisions and therefore are based on society’s values.  In essence, the environment itself is not being valued, instead individual preferences for the environment are what are being measured and compared.   Environmental valuation can be a useful, yet also difficult and controversial tool.
There are two types of values: use and non-use. ‘Use value’ is defined as the value derived from the actual use of a good or service, such as hunting, fishing, bird-watching, or hiking.  Use values may also include ‘indirect uses,’ such as the value of a bug that a fish may eat, which then a fisherperson may catch.  Though that bug is not directly used by the fisherperson, it has an indirect value because of its place in the food chain.  A large part of environmental economics has been devoted to valuing ‘use’ services.
‘Non-use values,’ also referred to as ‘passive use’ values, are values that are not associated with actual use, or even the option to use a good or service.  Existence value is a type of non-use value and is the value that people place on simply knowing that something exists, even if they will never see it or use it.   Many people value the Amazon rainforest, even though they may never go there.  Non-use value is the most difficult type of value to estimate.
Total economic value is the sum of all the relevant use and non-use values for a good or service.

How is valuation used? – Cost/Benefit Analysis

The main method used for valuation is cost-benefit analysis (CBA).  This analysis is basically compiling the costs of a project as well as the benefits, then translating them into monetary terms and discounting them over time.  (Discounting is the process of determining the present value of future benefits and costs.)  Ideally, only projects with benefits greater than costs would be acceptable.

Cost - benefit comparisons have some problems.  First, environmental benefits often lack market value, yet their costs are known.  Second, benefits are often collected over time, while costs are up front.  This creates a dilemma, since the question to be answered is in present time. Third, it is often difficult to understand what is being measured or to determine values for what is being measured. And fourth, results are often controversial and in some cases, could be used against you.  However, it is good to remember that you are empowered just by describing each benefit, even if you can’t value it.   

The first step is always to compare what would happen with and without the proposed project.  Economic analysis is not possible without a clear understanding of how the project would affect the area.  When this exercise is complete, the analyst should have a list of project impacts, classified according to the type of value they are likely to affect (use or non-use) and the group or groups that would benefit from the project.  
There are several different methodologies used to determine the value of a benefit.  Which methodology is used is often determined by the time and expense of the analysis.  

The following methods are used:

 1.) Market Price Method
Estimates economic values for ecosystem products or services that are bought and sold in commercial markets.  For example, a cultural site could be valued based on the entrance fees collected.
2.) Productivity Method
Estimates economic values for ecosystem products or services that contribute to the production of commercially marketed goods.  For example, the benefits of different levels of water quality improvement would be compared to the costs of reductions in polluting runoff.
3.) Hedonic Pricing Method
Estimates economic values for ecosystem or environmental services that directly affect market prices of some other good. Most commonly applied to variations in housing prices that reflect the value of local environmental attributes.
4.) Travel Cost Method
Estimates economic values associated with ecosystems or sites that are used for recreation. Assumes that the value of a site is reflected in how much people are willing to pay to travel to visit the site.  For example, adding up the costs people would expend to travel and recreate at a particular area.
5.) Damage Cost Avoided, Replacement Cost, and Substitute Cost Methods
Estimate economic values based on costs of avoided damages resulting from lost ecosystem services, costs of replacing ecosystem services, or costs of providing substitute services. For example, the costs avoided by providing flood protection.
6.) Contingent Valuation Method
Estimates economic values for virtually any ecosystem or environmental service. The most widely used method for estimating non-use, or “passive use” values. It asks people to directly state their willingness to pay for specific environmental services, based on a hypothetical scenario.  For example, people would state how much they would pay to protect a particular area.
7.) Contingent Choice Method
Estimates economic values for virtually any ecosystem or environmental service. Based on asking people to make tradeoffs among sets of ecosystem or environmental services or characteristics. It does not directly ask for willingness to pay—this is inferred from tradeoffs that include cost as an attribute.  For example, a person would state their preference between various locations for siting a landfill.
8.) Benefit Transfer Method
Estimates economic values by transferring existing benefit estimates from studies already completed for another location or issue.  For example, an estimate of the benefit obtained by tourists viewing wildlife in one park might be used to estimate the benefit obtained from viewing wildlife in a different park. 

The researcher should first narrow the types of benefits by their importance and then balance accuracy and costs in choosing methods.  Sometimes the easiest analysis often provides substantial benefits that show large values.  Usually, a benefit measured from market-based techniques or various kinds of extractive use values are the easiest to measure.  If one method alone provides an answer, then the analysis can stop.  The data requirements and limitations of the methods should be taken into account when deciding which to use. Discounting, which is the process of reducing future benefits and costs to their present value, is the last step.  Choosing an acceptable discount rate is often a challenging task.  It is highly controversial since the rate chosen will have a big effect on the results of the analysis.  Sometimes the discount rate is chosen by federal regulation.
Once more it should be noted that:

“Because it focuses only on economic benefits and costs, benefit-cost analysis 
determines the economically efficient option.  This may or may not be the same as 
the most socially acceptable option, or the most environmentally beneficial option.  
Remember, economic values are based on peoples’ preferences, which may not 
coincide with what is best, ecologically, for a particular ecosystem.  However, public 
decisions must consider public preferences, and benefit-cost analysis based on 
ecosystem valuation is one way to do so.”  


No comments:

Post a Comment